Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Lobbying on Accounting Regulation: Evidence from the Oil Industry1 * Paper presented at the VII Congresso Anpcont, Fortaleza, Brazil, 2013.

Abstracts

This work aims to identify the determining factors in the submission of comment letters to the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) on the discussion paper Extractive Activities as a lobbying strategy in the context of accounting regulation. The results show that size is a determining factor in all models used, indicating that large oil companies are more likely to lobby. This tendency is especially evident for companies that are predominantly opposed to the IASB proposals, which suggests that the IASB's review/replacement of International Financial Reporting Standards 6 (IFRS 6) will be a complex process subject to pressure from oil companies to maintain the status quo.

Lobbying; Accounting regulation; Oil industry; Accounting choices


Este trabalho tem como objetivo identificar os fatores determinantes à submissão de cartas comentários, como estratégia de lobbying no contexto da regulação contábil, à audiência pública do Discussion Paper Extractive Activities do International Accounting Standards Board IASB).Os resultados mostram o tamanho como fator determinante, em todas as modelagens utilizadas, indicando que grandes empresas petrolíferas possuem maior probabilidade para realizar lobbying. Essa propensão é verificada para posicionamentos essencialmente desfavoráveis às propostas apresentadas pelo IASB, o que implica em considerar que a revisão/substituição do International Financial Reporting Standard -IFRS6 será um processo complexo e sujeito a pressões por parte das empresas petrolíferas para manter o status quo.

Lobbying; Regulação contábil; Setor petrolífero; Escolhas contábeis


1 INTRODUCTION

In the field of accounting regulation of oil exploration and production activities, the debate overwhich accounting model best captures economic transactions in the oil industry dates back to the 1960s and 1970s. Even in the U.S., which has been a pioneer in the development of the theoretical and normative frameworks of accounting in the oil industry, both the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) have disagreed with each otherabout the appropriate standards for the oil industry; as a result, two conflicting accounting methods have been allowed tocoexist in the U.S.: the "successful efforts" method and the "full cost" method (Cortese, Irvine, & Kaidonis, 2009Cortese, C. L., Irvine, H. J., & Kaidonis, M. A. (2009). Extractive industries accounting and economic consequences: past, present and future. Accounting Forum, 33,27-37.).

This scenario, in which oil companies can freely choose between two different accounting methods, was the result of an intense lobbying campaign by oil and gas companies that effectively pitted the FASB and the SEC against each other. On one side, the FASB defended the successful efforts method in its Statements of Financial Accounting Standard no. 19 - Financial Accounting and Reporting by Oil and Gas Producing Companies (SFAS 19); on the other side, the SEC defended the full cost method in its Regulation SX 4-10. The two accounting standards continue to coexist in the U.S. today.

The same situation exists within the context of international standard setting, wherein attempts since 1998 to develop a single international accounting standard for the oil industry have been unsuccessful. In 2004, the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) issued International Financial Reporting Standards 6 - Exploration for and Evaluation of Mineral Resources (IFRS 6) to provide guidance to extractive companies listed in the European Union, which were required to adopt International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) in 2005. Although IFRS 6 provided general guidelines for the different accounting methods used by international companies in extractive industries, it did not address the merits of each method and did not indicate which method should be adopted by international companies.

More than six years have passed since the issuance of IFRS 6, and discussions relating to the issuance of definitive international accounting standardsfor extractive industries are still ongoing. In this regard, the discussion paper Extractive Activities (DPEA), which was published by the IASB as part of its IFRS 6 review/replacement project, presents and discusses ten key questions regarding the recognition, measurement and disclosure of financial events relating to extractive activities.

With respect to the accounting regulation process, this study is based onthe economic theory of regulation and the proposition of Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134. that agents have economic incentives to influence regulatory bodies through lobbying to obtain regulatory standards that satisfy their interests. This study thus aims to answer the following research question: what are the determining factors in the submission of comment lettersto lobby on accounting regulation of the oil industry?

The objective is to identify the determining factors in lobbying strategies in accounting regulation of the oil industry to ascertain the key features that cause interest groups comprising oil companies' financial statement preparers to try to influence the IASB by submitting comment letters to public comment period.

To achieve the proposed goal, multivariate data analysis techniques (binomial and multinomial logistic regressions and Poisson regression) are used to ascertain whether there is correlation between variables representing firms' characteristics and the submission of comments on the DPEA to the IASB. The study therefore aims to define the factors that determine the adoption of this lobbying strategy for the oil industry's accounting regulation process.

Econometric modeling is conducted for a sample comprising both lobbying oil companies (those that submitted comment letters to the IASB) and non-lobbying oil companies (those that did not submit comment letters) to identify the preponderant economic factors involved in the adoption of lobbying strategies by such interest groups (oil companies) before the IASB.

This research strategy has been used to identify the reasons for lobbying and the lobbying strategies adopted by various interest groups in numerous studies, including the studies of Dhaliwal (1982)Dhaliwal, D. S. (1982). Some economic determinants of management lobbying for alternative methods of accounting: evidence from the accounting for interest costs issue. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 9(2),255-265., Sutton (1984)Sutton, T. G. (1984). Lobbying of accounting standard-setting bodies in the U.K. and the U.S.A.: a Downsian analysis., Accounting, Organizations and Society 9(1),81-95., Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57., Deakin (1989)Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151., Kenny and Larson (1993)Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554., Tutticci, Dunstan and Holmes (1994)Tutticci, I., Dunstan, K., & Holmes, S. (1994). Respondent lobbying in the Australian accounting standard-setting process: ED49 - a case study. Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 7(2),86-104 ., Weetman, Davie and Collins (1996)Weetman, P., Davie, E. S., & Collins, W. (1996). Lobbying on accounting issues: prepar/user imbalance in the case of the operating and financial review., Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 9(1),59-76., Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453., Asekomeh, Russel and Tarbert (2006)Asekomeh, A. O., Russel, A., & Tarbert, H. (2006). A critical analysis of the use of accounting standards' comment letters as lobbying tools by extractive industry firms. Petroleum Accounting and Financial Management Journal, 25(3),55-57., Hansen (2011)Hansen, T. B. (20011). Lobbying of the IASB: an empirical investigation. Journal of International Accounting Research, 10(2),57-75. and Ginner and Arce (2012), among others.

In this regard, it is necessary to clarify that the concept of lobbying employed in this study is very particular and refers to explicit statements contained incomment letters submitted at public consultation on accounting standards, as in the case of the DPEA.

However, analysis of the modus operandi of the IASB in issuing an IFRS, for example, reveals that the lobbying process does not only occur via the submission of comment letters. A number of lobbying strategies are possible, including those listed below:

  1. participation in meetings with boardor staff members, whether formal or informal, in-person or remote (e.g., videoconferences);

  2. participation in public sessions (round-tables) or field visits (outreach) during the established public comment period;

  3. appointing members to the sponsor foundation and its various bodies, such as the board andits technical or advisory committees (e.g., the IFRS Advisory Council, IFRS Interpretation Committeeand the new Accounting Standards Advisory Forum (ASAF), which is a consultative forum wherein members attempt to contribute to the development of globally accepted,high-quality normative standards) or even participation in different working groups;

  4. funding for the sponsors of the regulatory bodies;

  5. use of audit firms and professional associations as mediators before the board; and

  6. other strategies, including surveys and leafleting, among others.

Orens, Jorissen, Lybaert and Tas (2011)Orens, R., Jorissen, A., Lybaert, N., & Tas, L. V. D. (2011). Corporate lobbying in private accounting standard setting: does the IASB have to reckon with national differences? Accounting in Europe, 8(2),211-234. developed a schematic diagram that describes a set of lobbying strategies that can be used during different stages of the IASB's standard-setting process, as shown in Table 1.

Table 1
Methods of participation to influence the IASB

Notwithstanding this acknowledgment that 'lobbying' is a much more comprehensive concept in practice, due to methodological constraints,this study considers a lobbying strategy to be a strategy that uses the submission of public comment letters in response to public consultation of standard-setting bodies.

In defense of the use of comment letters to assess lobbying activities, Asekomeh et al.(2006)Asekomeh, A. O., Russel, A., & Tarbert, H. (2006). A critical analysis of the use of accounting standards' comment letters as lobbying tools by extractive industry firms. Petroleum Accounting and Financial Management Journal, 25(3),55-57. argue that unlike responses to questionnaires, which can be skewed/biased, comment letters provided in response to questions raised in public consultation provide a more accurate picture of lobbying actions becausethe statements contained in comment letters contribute significantly to the understanding of the position of each agent involved in the standard-setting process.

Georgiou (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453. investigated the effectiveness of multiple lobbying methods,including but not limited to comment letters. The results showed that even when parties used other lobbying methods - such as intermediation by audit firms and meetings with the UK's Accounting Standards Board (UKASB) - these methods were significantly associated with use of comment letters. The author concluded that companies that submitted comment letters were more likely to use other, complementary lobbying methods than companies that did not submit comment letters (Georgiou, 2004Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453.).

The selection for this studyof the oil industry and, consequently, of the accounting standards applicable to the oil industry stems from the fact that historical evidence provided by Collins, Dent and O'Connor (1978)Collins, D. W., Dent, W. T., & O'Connor, M. (1978November/December). Market effects of the elimination of full cost accounting in the oil and gas industry. Financial Analysts Journal, 48-56.; Solomons (1978)Solomons, D. (1978). The politicization of accounting. Journal of Accountancy, 146(5),65-72.; Deakin (1979)Deakin, E. B. (1979). An analysis of differences between non-major oil firms using successful efforts and full cost methods. The Accounting Review, 54(4),722-734.; Collins, Rozeff and Salatka (1982); Deakin (1989); Zeff (2005)Zeff, S. A. (2005February). The evolution of U.S. GAAP: the political forces behind professional standards. The CPA Journal, 21-29.; and King (2006)King, T. A. (2006). More than a numbers game: a brief history of accounting. New Jersey: Wiley., among others, has shown that the U.S. regulatory framework applicable to accounting in the oil industry emerged as a result of a strong lobbying system thatexerted pressure and influence on the SEC and FASB. This phenomenon was also observed with respect to the issuance of IFRS 6 by the IASB. Specifically, Cortese, Irvine and Kaidonis (2010)Cortese, C. L., Irvine, H. J., & Kaidonis, M. A. (2010) Powerful players: how constituents captured the setting of IFRS 6, an accounting standard for extractive industries., Accounting Forum 34,76-88. presented evidence that demonstrated that the international accounting body was captured by the regulated companies, resulting in a standard that maintained the status quo (i.e., the free choice of accounting methods), which clearly serves the interests of the oil companies.

In this context, the publication of the DPEA provides another opportunity to observe lobbying by oil companies to influence the IASB's regulation of oil industry accounting. This is the basis for this study and the reason why it is important.

2 THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

According to Viscusi, Harrington and Vernon(2005)Viscusi, W. K., Harrington, J. E., Jr., & Vernon, J. M. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust. (4th ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press., the theory of regulation can be viewed from three angles: the public interest theory; the capture theory; and the economic theory of regulation, which is also known asthe interest group theory. This study adopts the perspective of the economic theory of regulation.

The basic assumption of the economictheory of regulation is that regulation is conducted to meet the needs and contribute to the welfare of the interest groups that exert the greatest pressure on standard setters (Viscusi, Harrington & Vernon, 2005Viscusi, W. K., Harrington, J. E., Jr., & Vernon, J. M. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust. (4th ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press.). Given this assumption, the economic theory of regulation is also known as the interest group theory. The main exponents of the economic theory of regulation are researchers Stigler (1971)Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation., The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1),3-21., Posner (1974)Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2),335-358., Peltzman (1976)Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2),211-240. and Becker (1983)Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98,371-400..

According tothe economic theory of regulation, regulation is performed to serve the interests of groups that are more politically effective in convincing regulators to act on their behalf. Watts and Zimmerman (1978Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., 1986)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall., in line with Stigler (1971)Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation., The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1),3-21., Peltzman (1976)Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2),211-240. and Posner (1974)Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2),335-358., assume that individuals act to maximize their own utility and, therefore, that the process of accounting regulation (standardization) is the result of a political process in which individuals and groups compete for wealth transfers.

Stigler (1971)Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation., The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1),3-21. and Peltzman (1976)Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2),211-240. argue that economic theory in the political process focuses on incentives for individuals to come together in groups in order to lobby (influence regulators) for transfers of wealth. Thus, according to Solomons (1978)Solomons, D. (1978). The politicization of accounting. Journal of Accountancy, 146(5),65-72., assuming that the standard-setting process is political, accounting standards are not necessarily guided by theoretical or technical issues but by the different interests of the affected parties, who exert pressure for individual gain.

According to Kothari, Ramanna and Skinner (2010)Kothari, S. P., Ramanna, K., & Skinner, D. J. (2010). Implications for GAAP from an analysis of positive research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50,246-286., regulators are endowed with their own ideologies, and standards are the joint result of the regulators' ideologies and the effects of the pressure (lobbying) exerted by special interest groups. Under this theory, lobbying is not viewed as an illegal or immoral activity but as a mechanism through which regulatorsare informed of companies' policies and practices.

The studies on lobbying in accounting regulationcan be considered a subset of the studies on accounting choice (Francis, 1987Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57.; Kenny and Larson, 1993Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.) because, according to Francis (2001)Francis, J. (2001). Discussion of empirical research on accounting choice., Journal of Accounting and Economics 31,309-319., lobbying activities represent only one dimension of accounting choice.

According to Fields, Lys and Vincent (2001)Fields, T. D., Lys, T. Z., & Vicent, L. (2001). Empirical research on accounting choice. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31,255-307., an accounting choice is a decision whose primary purpose is to influence (in form or in substance) the output of the accounting system. Based on this definition, the theory of accounting choice is linked with the theory of interest groups because accounting choiceis based on various existing economic incentives, and such incentives are present in the regulation process itself. Thus, managers lobby the standard-setting body at the origin of standard development to obtain standards that meet their interests from the outset.

Watts and Zimmerman (1986)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall. formulated three hypotheses regarding firms' accounting choicesthat are relevant to the accounting regulation process: (1) the management compensation hypothesis, which states that managers have incentives to make choices that maximize their compensation; (2) the debt covenant hypothesis, which predicts that managers will make choices that avoid violating the terms of a loan; and (3) the political cost hypothesis, which posits that managers make accounting choices that will avoid political and public scrutiny.

More specifically, the management compensation hypothesis,also known as the bonus plan hypothesis,states that managers who receive variable compensation (e.g., bonuses, stock or stock options) often use accounting methods that shift reported earnings from future periods to the current period, thereby increasing their variable compensation for the current period (Watts and Zimmerman, 1986Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.).

Regarding the debt covenant hypothesis, Watts and Zimmerman (1986) argue that managers of companies that have higher degrees of debt are more likely to use accounting methods that increase profits. The assumption is that the higher the debt level, the more the company will be stifled by restrictions and conditions imposed by creditors, and the more stringent the restrictions imposed by creditors, the greater the likelihood that the company will violate the restrictions. By increasing company profits, managers ultimately relax the restrictions imposed by creditors (Watts and Zimmerman, 1986Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.).

Under the political cost hypothesis, the authors assert that large companies tend to use accounting methods that reduce profits more often than small companies, because size influences the amount of political attention received by a company. The assumption is that higher profits may attract adverse attention from regulators, professional associations, media, environmentalists and consumer groups, among others (Watts and Zimmerman, 1986Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.).

Watts and Zimmerman (1978Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., 1986)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall. argue that regulation is performed according to the interests of groups that are more politically effective in convincing the regulator/standard setter to act on their behalf, which accords with the economic theory of regulation (Stigler 1971Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation., The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1),3-21., Peltzman, 1976Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2),211-240., Posner, 1974Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2),335-358.; Becker, 1983Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98,371-400.).

By aligning accounting choice with the process of accounting regulation, managers have economic incentives to lobby regulators against or for accounting standards that enable the managers to, e.g., reduce or defer the payment of taxes; reduce political costs and information production (disclosure); or increase the receipt of bonuses.

Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134. empirically tested the formulated hypotheses using discriminant analysis on a sample of 52 comment letters submitted by companies on the FASB discussion memorandum regarding the accounting standard for general price level adjustments,and they concluded that managers have economic incentives to participate in the standard-setting process by lobbying the regulator.

Several other studies on the subject of lobbying on accounting regulation have been conducted based on the work of Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134.. For example, Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57. and, later, Ndubizu, Choi and Jain (1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. investigated the issuance process of SFAS 87 (Employers'Accounting for Pensions). In the first study, Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57. formulated a logit model that was applied to a sample of 218 companies that submitted comment letters on the FASB's preliminary views of SFAS 87 (lobbying companies) and 582 other companies (non-lobbying companies). The authors formulated hypotheses for size, debt (as aproxy for the effects of the standard on the balance sheet) and pension expense (as a proxy for the effects of the standard on the financial statement). The results indicated that size is not the only important factor in the decision to lobby a standard-setting body; rather, there is also the possibility that the new standardwill have adverse effects on financial statements.

Ndubizu et al. (1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. investigated the exposure draft step of SFAS 87 using a sample of 1,802 firms, including 156 lobbying companies who spoke against the exposure draft and 1,646 other (non-lobbying) companies. The results of Ndubizu et al. (1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. differed from those reported by Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57. in that Ndubizu et al. (1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. found that only earnings volatility - a variable not included in the previous study - was relevant in explaining the decision to submit comments on the exposure draft. This result confirmed the formulated hypothesis that companies with high earnings volatility prior tothe adoption of a new standard aremore likely to lobby.

Deakin's (1989)Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151. work sought to study the process of accounting regulation in the oil industry for companies that made submissions to the FASB. The author used a sample of companies that used the full cost method because these companies would be most affected by the FASB proposal. To define the dependent variable, the author classified companies as lobbying (those submitting comments on the FASB discussion memorandum or exposure draft) and non-lobbying (those not submitting any comments). The author used a logistic regression model to test hypotheses related to the existence of restrictive financial covenants and performance-based management compensation plans and found that the empirical evidence was consistent with these hypotheses.

Also noteworthy is the study by Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453. that analyzed the behavior of companies that lobbied the UKASB on the "deferred tax" standard. Their results indicated that the size and behavior of a company in past public consultation (frequency of lobbying) were key factors in the decision to submit comments to the UKASB on deferred taxes. Their results also indicated that companies submitting comments against the proposed standard were more likely to have contracts with debt covenants than companies in favor of the proposed standard.

Finally, their evidence showed that companies with performance-based management compensation plans were more likely to provide comments in favor of the proposal than companies without performance-based management compensation plans (Georgiou and Roberts, 2004Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453.).

More recently, the process of lobbying on accounting regulation has been studied from the perspective of institutional theory (Bengtsson, 2011Bengtsson, E. (2011). Repoliticalization of accounting standard setting - the IASB, the EU and the global financial crisis. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 22,567-580.; Chatham, Larsonand Vietze, 2010Chatham, M. D., Larson, R. K., & Vietze, A. (2010). Issues affecting the development of an international accounting standard on financial instruments. Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting, 26,97-107.; Fogarty, 1992Fogarty, T. J. (1992). Financial accounting standard setting as an institutionalized action field: constraints, opportunities and dilemmas. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 11,331-355.; Giner and Arce, 2012Giner, B., & Arce, M. (2012). Lobbying on accounting standards: evidence from IFRS 2 on share-based payments. European Accounting Review, 21(4),655-691.; Kenny and Larson, 1993Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.; Koh, 2011Koh, W. C. (2011). What drives firms' decisions to lobby and determinants of their lobbying positions: evidence from firms' comment letter submissions during FASB's stock option expensing proposal in 2004. The International Journal of Accounting, 46,1-24.; Larson 2002Larson, R. K. (2002). The IASC's search for legitimacy: an analysis of the IASC's Standing Interpretations Committee. Advances in International Accounting, 15,79-120., 2008Larson, R. K. (2008). An examination of comment letters to the IASC: special purpose entities. Research in Accounting Regulation, 20,27-46.; Larson and Kenny, 2011Larson, R. K., & Kenny, S. Y. (2011). Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 20,1-19.). This theory suggests that the actions of organizations should be understood as attempts to obtain legitimacy and to maintain credibility with external constituents (Fogarty, 1992Fogarty, T. J. (1992). Financial accounting standard setting as an institutionalized action field: constraints, opportunities and dilemmas. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 11,331-355.).

Tavares, Paulo, Anjos and Carter (2013)Tavares, M. F. N., Paulo, E., Anjos, L. C. M., & Carter, D. (2013). Contribuições ao exposure draft revenue from contracts with costumers: análise das opiniões das firmas sobre a obrigação de desempenho onerosa. Revista de Contabilidade do Mestrado em Ciências Contábeis da UERJ, 18(2),14-27. reiterated Riahi-Belkaouri's (2004) assertion that the promulgation of a standard is a social choice that forces regulators to adopt a political process aimed at accommodating various interests, including their own. In other words, according to institutional theory, the regulator is motivated to adopt strategies that will maintain its power and credibility in the community and facilitate the re-election of its members.

Institutional theory places organizations within a social setting and explicitly recognizes the influence of the external social environment on the internal activities of an organization, which seeks to obtain legitimacy or to retain social acceptance (Kenny and Larson, 1993Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.).

In this context, organizations such as the IASB seek legitimacy from their constituents in order to survive. The solicitation of comments on its products (accounting standards) from interested parties is one strategy employed by the IASB in its quest for legitimacy (Kenny and Larson, 1993Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.).

Consequently, various interest groups, which also seek legitimacy and recognition from their peers, can freely participate in the standard-setting process of these regulatory bodies, even when the interest groups are not directly affected by a normative proposal (Chatham et al., 2010Chatham, M. D., Larson, R. K., & Vietze, A. (2010). Issues affecting the development of an international accounting standard on financial instruments. Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting, 26,97-107.).

Given that the standard-setting process is a political one, organizations such as the IASB must continuously monitor the needs of their constituents and adjust their operations to accommodate those needs (Kenny and Larson, 1993Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.; Larson and Kenny, 2011Larson, R. K., & Kenny, S. Y. (2011). Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 20,1-19.).

According to Bengtsson (2011)Bengtsson, E. (2011). Repoliticalization of accounting standard setting - the IASB, the EU and the global financial crisis. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 22,567-580., institutional theory has been used in studies on accounting standard setting to complement the explanatory framework of political economy (from which the economic theory of regulation follows), and the focus of these studies has been on how external pressures influence the adoption of accounting standards.

Because this study is based on a discussion paper (the DPEA), it is not yet possible to know which opinions will ultimatelybe accepted or rejected by the IASB. To understand the accommodations that are made, this study uses the assumptions of institutional theory to complement the notions that participation in the public consultation process (lobbying) is legitimate and that companies seek to promote their accounting choices in the regulatory process. The study then turns to the economic theory of regulation to identify factors that lead companies to participate in the regulatory process.

A summary of the major studies on the topic is shown in Table 2.

Table 2
Studies on lobbying in accounting regulation

The cited studies, especially those by Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57., Deakin (1989), Ndubizu et al.(1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. and Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453. are methodologically aligned with the objective of this work, which is to establish the determining factors that led oil companies to submit comments on the DPEA, i.e., to lobby.

3 METHODOLOGY

The following research strategies are used to identify the determinant factors of lobbying activity on accounting regulation in the oil industry.

Based on the 141 comment letters published by the IASB on its website, the first step is to perform content analysis of the letters submitted by oil companies to measure the dependent variable used in the econometric models.

The second step of the study is based on quantitative analysis and uses econometric models to identify the economic factors that determine the adoption of a lobbying strategy that employs the submission of comment letters.

Depending on the characteristics of the dependent variable, binomial and multinomial logistic regressions and Poisson regression are used. In the case of binomial regressions, the dependent variable takes a value of "1" where comments on the DPEA have been submitted and a value of "0" otherwise.

In multinomial logistic regression, the dependent variable is decomposed into three categories: "0" to represent companies that submitted no comments on the DPEA; "1" to represent the companies that submitted predominantly favorable comments; and "2" to represent companies that submitted predominantly unfavorable comments.

Finally, Poisson regression is employed when the dependent variable is intended to express the degree of agreement or disagreement with the ten questions presented in the DPEA. Thus, it can take values from zero, in the case of companies that submitted no comments, up to ten, which represents the maximum number of times a company could agree or disagree with the proposals addressed in the DPEA questions.

3.1 Definition of Variables and Research Hypotheses.

As stated earlier, the dependent variable used as a proxy for lobbying refers to the explicit statements contained in comment letters submitted to the public consultation on the DPEA. This model has been widely used in accounting studies on lobbying, including studies by Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57., Deakin (1989), Ndubizu et al. (1993)Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. and Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453..

In this study, lobbying strategies are limited to comment letters because the use of other lobbying strategies to measure the dependent variable usually involves private information, which makes modeling difficult to implement (Holthausen and Leftwich, 1983Holthausen, R. W., & Leftwich, R. W. (1983 August). The economic consequences of accounting choice: implications of costly contracting and monitoring., Journal of Accounting and Economics 5,77-117.). Although the exclusive use of comment letters is an inherent limitation of the present study, several studies have defended this modeling approach, including Asekomeh et al. (2006)Asekomeh, A. O., Russel, A., & Tarbert, H. (2006). A critical analysis of the use of accounting standards' comment letters as lobbying tools by extractive industry firms. Petroleum Accounting and Financial Management Journal, 25(3),55-57., Chung (1999)Chung, D. Y. (1999). The informational effect of corporate lobbying against proposed accounting standards. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 12(3),243-269., Sutton (1984)Sutton, T. G. (1984). Lobbying of accounting standard-setting bodies in the U.K. and the U.S.A.: a Downsian analysis., Accounting, Organizations and Society 9(1),81-95. and Georgiou (2004)Georgiou, G. (2004). Corporate lobbying on accounting standards: methods, timing and perceived effectiveness. Abacus, 40(2),219-237.. Thus, this modeling approach is adopted for the present study.

Accordingly, depending on the type of regression used, the dependent variable has the characteristics listed in Table 3.

Table 3
Characteristics of the dependent variable

Regarding the independent variables, size has often been usedin the literature on lobbying on accounting regulation to express a company's exposure (political cost hypothesis) (Watts and Zimmerman, 1978Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134.; Francis, 1987Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57.; Deakin, 1989Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151.; Ndubizu, Choi and Jain, 1993Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287. and Georgiou and Roberts, 2004Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453.).

Size has also been associated with the hypothesis that a lobbying strategy is only adopted if the benefits of lobbying outweigh the costs (Sutton, 1984Sutton, T. G. (1984). Lobbying of accounting standard-setting bodies in the U.K. and the U.S.A.: a Downsian analysis., Accounting, Organizations and Society 9(1),81-95.). In this sense,Koh (2011)Koh, W. C. (2011). What drives firms' decisions to lobby and determinants of their lobbying positions: evidence from firms' comment letter submissions during FASB's stock option expensing proposal in 2004. The International Journal of Accounting, 46,1-24. states that because large companies have more resources, they usually tend to influence the final result and hence reap the benefits of lobbying.

To operationalize the size variable the following four proxies were used: net revenue for the period (NETREV); total assets for the period (TOTASS); average net profit for the last three periods (AVPROF); and exploration and development costs incurred in the period (UPSTREAM). The test hypothesis for size is defined as:

H1: Large oil companies are more likely to lobby, whether for or against the proposed standard, than other oil companies.

The extant literature presents two other variables representing economic incentives for accounting choice (in this case, the decision to lobby the standard-setting body). First, it is assumed that managers of companies with performance-based compensation plans that depend on indicators derived from financial information tend to choose accounting models that benefit themselves. In other words, these companies will opt for proposed standards that incorporate accounting methods that increase or diminish profits, according to their respective interests.

The second characteristic is the existence of restrictive debt covenants. This theory holds that managers tend to choose accounting standards that result in the non-violation of those covenants. Thus, the closer the company is to a covenant threshold based on accounting numbers, the greater the probability that the manager will use accounting procedures that increase revenue and/or reduce the level of debt (Holthausen and Leftwich, 1983Holthausen, R. W., & Leftwich, R. W. (1983 August). The economic consequences of accounting choice: implications of costly contracting and monitoring., Journal of Accounting and Economics 5,77-117.).

To operationalize these two characteristics, the MANCOMP and COVENANT binary variables are used, which take the value of "0" in cases in which the company does not have the characteristic of interest and the value of "1" in cases in which the company has the characteristic of interest. These variables are measured by searching the explanatory notes to companies' financial statements (available on their websites) for references to the existence (or absence) of performance-based management compensation plans and restrictive debt covenants.

These variables can be operationalized in different ways, and the binary coding of "0" or "1" for these variables based on the existence or absence of the testable characteristic is a limitation of the study. This is because the manner in which binary variables are operationalized cannot properly capture the magnitude of the characteristic they aim to investigate. Deakin (1989)Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151., Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453., Georgiou (2005)Georgiou, G. (2005). Investigating corporate management lobbying in the U.K. accounting standard-setting process: a multi-issue/multi-period approach., Abacus 41(3),323-347. and Koh (2011)Koh, W. C. (2011). What drives firms' decisions to lobby and determinants of their lobbying positions: evidence from firms' comment letter submissions during FASB's stock option expensing proposal in 2004. The International Journal of Accounting, 46,1-24. are examples of studies that offer alternative methods of operationalizing these variables.

The testable hypotheses are:

H2: Oil companies with performance-based management compensation plans are more likely to lobby, whether in favor of or against the proposed standard, than oil companies without performance-based management compensation plans.

H3: Oil companies with restrictive debt covenants are more likely to lobby, whether in favor of or against the proposed standard, than oil companies without restrictive debt covenants.

To capture the risk of possible changes in the accounting regulation of the oil industry, the test model also considers the USLISTING and METHOD variables. Current international accounting regulation applicable to extractive activities is based on the IFRS 6 standard, which states that extractive companies can freely define their respective accounting policies. In practice, IFRS 6 does not mandate any specific method for asset recognition and measurement. As a result, companies subject to international standards ultimately choose between one of the two best-known international accounting methods, namely, the successful efforts and full cost methods, both of which were established by the United States.

Such an attitude can be understood from the perspective of institutional theory and the concept of mimetic isomorphism in particular. According to the concept of mimetic isomorphism, organizations tend to copy the practices of other organizations, particularly within the same industry, even when the organizations are not required to follow specific standards (Koh, 2011Koh, W. C. (2011). What drives firms' decisions to lobby and determinants of their lobbying positions: evidence from firms' comment letter submissions during FASB's stock option expensing proposal in 2004. The International Journal of Accounting, 46,1-24.).

The adoption of the successful efforts or full cost method is therefore a global reality and facilitates the publication of financial statements by non-US companies in the U.S. when, for example, non-U.S. companies are traded on the New York stock exchange.

The use of the USLISTING variable aims to capture the risk of possible changesin accounting regulation from the perspectives of both U.S. companies and non-U.S. companies whose stocks aretraded on the U.S. market.

In the case of U.S. companies, although there is no clear expectation that the U.S. will adopt the IFRS for U.S. companies, the evidence shows that the participation of U.S. companies in the process of IASB standard-setting is relevant; in some cases,U.S. companies are the parties with the greatest involvement in IASB public consultation (Larson, 1997Larson, R. K. (1997). Corporate lobbying of the international accounting standards committee. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, 8(3),175-203.; Larson and Kenny, 2011Larson, R. K., & Kenny, S. Y. (2011). Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 20,1-19.; Giner and Arce, 2012Giner, B., & Arce, M. (2012). Lobbying on accounting standards: evidence from IFRS 2 on share-based payments. European Accounting Review, 21(4),655-691.).

In the present study, 27 letters (19%) of the 141 letters received by the IASB on the DPEA were from interested U.S. parties. Thus, U.S. parties were second only to European parties, who submitted 76 letters.

Giner and Arce (2012)Giner, B., & Arce, M. (2012). Lobbying on accounting standards: evidence from IFRS 2 on share-based payments. European Accounting Review, 21(4),655-691. analyzed the IFRS 2 issuance process and showed that 264 of the 539 letters received by the IASB were submitted by U.S. companies. They argued that the strong participation by U.S. companies in the IASB's standard-setting process was motivated by fears about the possibility that the FASB and SEC will change their position regarding the adoption of IFRS for domestic companies (Giner and Arce, 2012Giner, B., & Arce, M. (2012). Lobbying on accounting standards: evidence from IFRS 2 on share-based payments. European Accounting Review, 21(4),655-691.).

From the perspective of non-U.S. companies that adopt IFRS, Larson (1997)Larson, R. K. (1997). Corporate lobbying of the international accounting standards committee. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, 8(3),175-203. and Georgiou (2005)Georgiou, G. (2005). Investigating corporate management lobbying in the U.K. accounting standard-setting process: a multi-issue/multi-period approach., Abacus 41(3),323-347. argued that changes in international standards can increase transaction costs by requiring accounting adjustments and the disclosure of additional information to meet the needs of U.S. investors. Thus, non-U.S. companies have an incentive to lobby the IASBto maintain the status quo.

Therefore, this study considers that U.S. oil companies and oil companies that trade on the U.S. stock market have an incentive to lobby the IASB to maintain the status quo, i.e., to maintain the companies' freedom to choose between the successful efforts and full cost methods, and thereby avoid the possible transaction costs associated with convergence to new standards. The test hypothesis corresponds to:

H4: Oil companies listed on the U.S. stock market are more likely to lobby against the proposed standard than oil companies not listed on the U.S. stock market.

One of the proposals under consideration by the IASB establishes a new method for asset recognition and measurement applicable to extractive activities and eliminates the choice between the successful efforts and full cost methods.

The IASB's proposal would establish that the legal right to exploit natural resources is the key basis for the recognition of assets and that other costs incurred to confirm and ensure the commercial exploitation of resources are enhancements of that legal right. Thus, this scenario is a departure from the experience of companies accustomed to the successful efforts or full cost method.

Zeff (2002)Zeff, S. A. (2002). "Political" lobbying on proposed standards: a challenge to the IASB., Accounting Horizons 16(1),43-54. argued that the setting of a new standard that eliminates choice or imposes additional disclosure requirements is a trigger for constituents to put pressure on the standard setter to meet their needs. This argument is also found in Saemann (1999)Saemann, G. (1999). An examination of comment letters filed in the U.S. financial accounting standard-setting process by institutional interest groups. Abacus, 35(1),1-28., who maintained that such a scenario typically leads interested parties to oppose the standard setter's proposals.

Tavares et al. (2013)Tavares, M. F. N., Paulo, E., Anjos, L. C. M., & Carter, D. (2013). Contribuições ao exposure draft revenue from contracts with costumers: análise das opiniões das firmas sobre a obrigação de desempenho onerosa. Revista de Contabilidade do Mestrado em Ciências Contábeis da UERJ, 18(2),14-27. argued that regulation restricts accounting choice to the extent that the regulator has the power to decide the accounting policies that regulated companies should follow.

In this context, the DPEA proposal eliminates oil companies' choice by establishing a single method of asset recognition and measurement. Thus, under Zeff's (2002)Zeff, S. A. (2002). "Political" lobbying on proposed standards: a challenge to the IASB., Accounting Horizons 16(1),43-54. theory, companies have an incentive to lobby the IASB to maintain the status quo. This incentive is also supported in Watts and Zimmerman (1978Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., 1986)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall., who argue that financial statement preparers consider the potential impact of a new accounting approach on expected future cash flows when deciding whether to lobby.

As discussed in Santos, Lopes and Silva (2010)Santos, O. M., Lopes, A. B., & Silva, P. D. A. (2010 julho). Value relevance dos métodos contábeis full cost e successful effort sem empresas petrolíferas e considerações sobre a futura norma internacional das atividades extrativistas. Anais do Congresso USP de Controladoria e Contabilidade, São Paulo, SP, Brasil, 10., companies that follow the successful efforts method would be most affected by the proposal in the DPEA because adoption of this proposal would lead to significant changes in the accounting policies of these companies. Accordingly, it is expected that companies using the successful efforts method are more likely to lobby against the proposals in the DPEA.

Thus, the METHOD variable aimsto determine whether there is an association between the choice of the successful efforts method (labeled "1") and the probability of submitting comments against the DPEA. The testable hypothesis corresponds to:

H5: Oil companies using the successful efforts method are more likely to lobby against the proposed standard than oil companies using the full cost method.

3.2 Specification of Econometric Models.

The reasoning presented above leads to the following econometric model:

where i represents the company, and LOBBYING takes the value "l" for companies who submitted comments on the DPEA and the value "0" for companies that did not submit comments. The error term of the regression is indicated by parameter ε; α is the intercept; and β12, β3, ..., β8 are the estimated coefficients, which are expected to be statistically significant and positive.

According to Favero, Belfiore, Silva and Chan (2009), the analysis of the results focuses on the coefficients of the independent variables (β), which must be statistically relevant, and is based on the idea that when the coefficient is greater than zero, the probability of occurrence of the event of interest (i.e., lobbying on the DPEA) is greater, and vice versa.

The multinomial logistic regression has the following specification:

where LOBBYING assumes a value of ​​"0" for companies that did not submit comments on the DPEA; "1" for companies that submitted comments that were predominantly in favor of the DPEA; and "2" for companies thatsubmitted commentsthat were predominantly against the DPEA.

The analyses are conducted by comparing (1) companies that submitted predominantly favorable comments to companies that did not submit comments and (2) companies that submitted predominantly unfavorable comments to companies that did not submit comments (Favero, Belfiore, Silva and Chan, 2009Fávero, L. P., Belfiore, P., Silva, F. L., & Chan, B. L. (2009). Análise de dados: modelagem multivariada para tomada de decisões. Rio de Janeiro: Elsevier.).

The Poisson regression model uses the following specification:

Where LOBBYING assumes values ​​ranging from "0" to "10", with "0" assigned to companies that did not submit comments on the DPEA and "10" being the maximum possible value of agreement (or disagreement) with respect to the DPEA.

To exemplify the use of these three models, suppose that a company submitted comments on the DPEA and that the company's responses to the 10 questions comprised 7 responses against the proposed standards and 3 responses in favor of the proposed standards. In the first model (binomial logistic regression), the company would be coded as "1" (submitted comments); in the multinomial logistic regression model, it would receive code "2" (predominantly against the proposed standards); and, finally, in the Poisson regression it would be coded as "3" in the "lobbying in favor" panel and "7" in the "lobbying against" panel.

3.3 Sample Characteristics.

Because the sample must contain both lobbying and non-lobbying companies, oil companies that submitted comment letters on the DPEA were identified. The IASB received 141 comment letters, of which 39 (28%) were submitted by extractive companies and 33 (23%) were submitted by non-governmental entities. The group comprising national issuers, accounting profession entities and capital market regulators contributed 25 letters (18%). The groups comprising investors/individual users, oil industry consulting firms/professional associations and audit firms submitted 17, 12 and 8 comment letters, respectively. Eight other letters were submitted by various stakeholders.

Of the 39 comment letters submitted to the IASB by extractive companies, 28 of the letters were from oil companies and 11 were from mining companies. Thus, the initial focus was on these 28 oil companies, 3 of which could not be used due to the unavailability of information necessary for the study.

The database of Evaluate Energy®, which is a leading consultancy firm that provides information about the oil and gas industry, was consulted. Because the DPEA was in public consultation from April to July 2010, industry information for 2009 was used. The Evaluate Energy ® database had 2009 information from 262 companies in the oil industry.

Because the Evaluate Energy® database does not include information necessary to operationalize the MANCOMP and COVENANT variables, a random selection from the 237 companies in the database (excluding the 25 already pre-selected to represent lobbying companies) was conducted to select non-lobbying companies.

To define the sample size for the random selection, the expression n = N x n0 / N + n0 was used, in which n0 = 1 / E20, where n0 is the first approximation of sample size; E20is the tolerable sampling error; N is the size of target population; and n is the sample size. Thus, for a target population (N) of 237 and tolerable sampling error (E20) of 6%, we arrive at 127 companies, which, when added to the 25 lobbying companies, yields a final sample of 152 oil and gas companies.

The sample comprises companies of different sizes, as shown in Table 4. For example, the averagenet revenue (NETREV) in 2009 was (in logarithmic values) USD 8.84 million. However, there is considerable variation between the minimum value of USD 2.42 million and the maximum value of USD 12.54 million, which provides a standard deviation of USD 1.95 million. The same behavior is observed for other variables, such as the average net profit (AVPROF), which range from a minimum value of USD 1.60 million to a maximum value of USD 20.7 million.

Table 4
Descriptive statistics of continuous variables

Although the assumption of normality of the residuals is not a requirement for logistic regression, the continuous variableswere natural-log transformed to achieve a normal distributionin an effort to mitigate possible "scale effects" in the regressions. As shown in Table 4, after transformation, only the UPSTREAM variable remained non-normally distributed.

Regarding the dichotomous variables (Table 5), 25 of the 152 sampled companies provided comments onthe DPEA to the IASB, corresponding to 16% of the sample. For the purposes of this study, these 25 companies are characterized as lobbying companies, where as the remaining companies in the sample are considered non-lobbying companies.

Table 5
Descriptive statistics of dichotomous variables

Regarding the COVENANT and MANCOMP variables, the sampled companies have almost the same distribution among those that have covenants (73%) or performance-based management compensation plans (74%) and those that do not.

As for the accounting methods used by companies in the sample, the results are balanced, with 51% of companies using the successful efforts method and 49% using the full cost method. Companies with stocks traded on the U.S. stock market constitutea majority of the sample, corresponding to 88 companies, or 58% of the sample.

Regarding the correlation between the variables, Table 6 shows that variables relating to size exhibit a reasonably statistically significant association with the dependent variable LOBBYING, with correlation ranging from 24% to 42%. Unexpectedly, such association is not observed with the other variables.

Table 6
Pearson correlation matrix

The correlation between the explanatory variables allows aninference on the assumption of multicollinearity. Specifically, the results show that the variables relating to size feature high degrees of significant associations, especially among NETREV, AVPROF and TOTASS, ranging from 77% to 89%, which indicates a possible violation of the assumption of multicollinearity.

As a result of the above, a model wasdeveloped containing all proxies for size, and the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) test was performed to analyze the assumption of multicollinearity. Other models were then constructed with only one of these proxiesto provide robustness to the analyses.

4 ANALYSIS OF RESULTS

It can be said that oil companies that submitted comment letters (lobbying companies in this study) were in favor of the proposals presented in four of ten the questions in the DPEA (the 1st, 6th, 7th and 8th questions), as shown in Table 7.

Table 7
Analysis of companies' positioning toward the DPEA

Companies were largely in favor of the notion that the scope of an extractive activities IFRS should be limited to upstream activities (1st question), and unanimously agreed that historical cost should be the basis for measuring the assets of the extractive sector, as opposed to the assets' fair value (6th question). On this point, it is important to note that the DPEA working group argued that although fair value would offer the best representation of relevant economic events and would provide more useful information to users, measurement based on fair value would be very complex and subjective. Accordingly, the DPEA working group concluded that historical cost should be the basis used by financial statement preparers, due to the lack of a better choice.

The majority of lobbying companies also agreed with the propositions relating to the applicability of the IAS 36 standard (7th question) and the objectives of financial statements prepared by extractive companies (8th question).

However, the results show largely unfavorable positions with respect tothe question regarding the possible adoption of a new and unique accounting method (and the implied elimination of the successful efforts and full cost methods) (4th question), as well as with respect to questions regarding proposals to increase the level of disclosure in the explanatory notes of financial statements (9th and 10th questions).

The main arguments presented by companies opposed to the adoption of a new accounting method and increased disclosure requirements were that the concept of assets contained in the DPEA damaged the conceptual framework by allowing costs that are unrelated to future economic benefits to be recognized; that the increased disclosure requirements would mandate the disclosure of too much information; and that the costs of producing the information required to be disclosed under the proposal in the DPEA would outweigh the benefits of its disclosure.

A review of all of the comments shows that there is almost a stalemate, with 115 opinions in favor of the propositions contained in the DPEA and 118 opinions against. However, when considering only the propositions that imply changes in the status quo (the establishment of a new asset recognition method, the adoption of the fair value basis, and an increase in mandatory disclosure items, i.e., the 4th, 5th, 6th, 7th, 9th and 10th questions), the results show that companies lobbied to reject any possibility of changing the status quo. Specifically, 107 opinions (71%) were in favor of maintaining the current situation, and only 39 (26%) argued in favor of the changes proposed in the DPEA.

These findings are consistent with the finding by Kenny and Larson (1993)Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554. thatlobbying companies act to avoid any change to the status quo, as well as with the argument of Holthausen and Leftwich (1983)Holthausen, R. W., & Leftwich, R. W. (1983 August). The economic consequences of accounting choice: implications of costly contracting and monitoring., Journal of Accounting and Economics 5,77-117. that possible changes to the status quo affect managers' decisions whether to lobby on accounting regulation.

Therefore, one can infer that the oil companies' current asset recognition model and the current disclosure requirements satisfy the needs of the oil companies. Thus, institutional theory suggests that any change to the status quo would have to be well "tailored" by the IASB to accommodate the needs of its diverse constituents, including the constituents most affectedby the proposed changes, i.e.,the oil companies.

To ascertain the main characteristics that led oil companies to submit comment letters on the DPEA, multivariate data analysis was conducted on the results described above. The logistic regression results are expressed in five regressions (Table 8). The first regression considers all model variables, where as the remaining regressions each consider one of the selected variables for the size hypothesis.

Table 8
Results of binomial logistic regression

Using a chi-square distribution, which is analogous to the F test for multiple regression, it is clear that the model variables are collectively significant from a statistical point of view, with an estimated likelihood ratio of 35.296 and a p-value of 0.000. Therefore, there is at least one nonzero coefficient at the 1% level.

The Nagelkerke measure resembles the R2 of a multiple regression and is used to measure the goodness-of-fit of the model. The result shows that the model has an explanatory power of 40.8%. Because this study is interested in the statistical significance of the coefficients of the variables used, and not necessarily in making predictions, this goodness-of-fit is consistent with the proposed objectives.

Another way to analyze the goodness-of-fit of the model is to check the extent to which the model correctly classifies events considering the cutoff point used, which in this study is 16.5% (i.e., the percentage of sampled companies that present the event of interest). The results indicate that the model correctly classified 76.3% of cases.

The ROC (Receiver Operating Characteristic) curve, which measures a model's discriminatory power, was also used to evaluate model fit. With a value of 86.9%, the final model specification has excellent discriminatory power according to the classifications of Favero et al. (2009)Fávero, L. P., Belfiore, P., Silva, F. L., & Chan, B. L. (2009). Análise de dados: modelagem multivariada para tomada de decisões. Rio de Janeiro: Elsevier., who state that an ROC curve less than or equal to 0.5 (50%) indicates no discrimination; an ROC curve between 0.5 and 0.8 (80%)indicates acceptable discrimination; and an ROC curve greater than 0.8 indicates excellent discrimination.

The results show that only the AVPROF variable is statistically significant within normally used levels. Because the estimated coefficient was greater than zero, the interpretation is that the higher the company's average net profit, the greater the likelihood that the company will lobby by comment letter.The estimated coefficient indicates that an increase of USD1 million in average net profit increases the logit by 0.348 or, calculating the antilogarithm, an increase in net profit increases the likelihood of lobbying by a factor of 1.416.

It is also possible to determine that the MANCOMP variable showed marginal statistical significance of 14.4%, which, although it is outside the usual levels, may be considered relevant depending on the risk.

Given the high correlation observed between the independent variables, especially those representing size (as shown in Table 6), the VIF test was used to formallyevaluate the assumption of multicollinearity. As suspected, this assumption was not met, due to thehigh VIF values for TOTASS and NETREV. The issue is that highly correlated independent variables provide similar information to explain and predict the dependent variable, which makes it difficult to separate the effects of each independent variable and causes one of them to lose significance in the explanation of the phenomenon under analysis (Corrar, Paulo, & Dias Filho, 2007Corrar, L. J., Paulo, E., & Dias Filho, J. M. (2007). Análise multivariada. São Paulo: Atlas.).

Because the presence of multicollinearity tends to distort the estimated slope coefficients, thereby hindering the assessment of the real effect of the independent variable on the phenomenon under investigation, the regression results of the first model are biased. This may explain the lack of statistical relevance of some of the independent variables and may even explain the negative sign of NETREV.

To work around this issue, new models were constructed, each including only one of the size variables. When variables related to size were placed in the model separately, each of them was statistically significant and the sign of the coefficient was as expected, which confirms the effect of multicollinearity.

The general parameters of the regressions remained practically stable from a qualitative point of view, which, when considering all of the variables, suggests that the models are statistically significant, in accordance with the likelihood ratio tests. Nagelkerke's R2 of the models was between 17.5% and 39.6%, and the ROC curves showed excellent discrimination (except for model 2, which had only acceptable discrimination - 66%).

The marginal relevance of the MANCOMP (10.9%) variable was observed again in model 4, which included the AVPROF variable as proxy for size. This suggests that oil companies with performance-based management compensation plans are more likely to lobby via comment letters than oil companies without performance-based management compensation plans. Further, oil companies with performance-based management compensation plans were more likely to lobby by a factor of 3.347 (antilogarithm of 1.208) compared tocompanies without performance-based management compensation plans.

The results support acceptance of the political cost hypothesis developed by Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., according to which large companies tend to lobby on accounting legislation to obtain results that are more favorable to them. The results are also consistent with the findings of Francis (1987)Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57., Deakin (1989) and Georgiou and Roberts (2004) regarding size. Thus, there is no evidence to reject hypothesis H1 based on binomial logistic regression modeling.

The binomial logistic regression also supports (albeit less convincingly) the theoretical hypothesis presented in the literature that company managers who receive performance-based compensation that depends on financial indicators tend to lobbyon legislation to obtain the accounting models that best benefit them.

The econometric model used here and in the majority of the studies on lobbying (Francis, 1987Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57.; Deakin, 1989Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151.; Ndubizu et al, 1993Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287.;Georgiou and Roberts, 2004Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453.) has been criticized because the binary dependent variable used in the model cannot capture the extent of the respondent's position (Holthausen and Leftwich, 1983Holthausen, R. W., & Leftwich, R. W. (1983 August). The economic consequences of accounting choice: implications of costly contracting and monitoring., Journal of Accounting and Economics 5,77-117.). Rather, the variable only captures whether comments are submitted (code 1) or not (code 0), or whether companies were in favor of (1) or against (0) the proposal.

Because the DPEA has ten questions, respondents may have provided comments in response to all of the questions or only to some of them, and may have been in favor of some of the proposals butagainst others. These situations are not captured by the binomial logistic regression model. To address this issue, a multinomial logistic regression model was used, the results of which are shown in Table 9.

Table 9
Results of multinomial logistic regression

The multinomial logistic regressions are arranged in two blocks. The first set contains the results of the comparison between oil companies in favor of the DPEA proposals and oil companies that did not submit comments on the DPEA, whereas the results of the second block refer to the comparison between oil companies opposed to the proposals in the DPEA and oil companies that did not submit comments.

In view of the multicollinearity issue, the multinomial logistic regressions were performed separately for each independent variable for size. The general parameters of the four regression models are valid because the chi-square test reveals a statistical significance at the 1% level. The goodness-of-fit of the models according to Nagelkerke's pseudo R2 varies between 33% and 41%, which are adequate values ​​for this study. Finally, over 85% of cases were correctly predicted, which indicates a good fit of the regressions performed.

Analyzing the estimated coefficients, the results show that the size variables in each model, apart from the constant, were statistically significant in both blocks of results (except for UPSTREAM in the first block), which reinforces the findings on the political cost hypothesis. It can therefore be inferred that large oil companies are more likely to lobby via comment letters than other oil companies.

A closer look at the likelihood of lobbying via comment letters indicates that this trend is greater for companies lobbying against the proposal, as demonstrated by the results obtained with increased net revenue. On the one hand, an increase in net revenue (NETREV) increases the likelihood of lobbying in favor of a proposal relative to not lobbyingby a factor of 1.421 (antilogarithm of 0.352). On the other hand, there is a 4.031 factor increase in the likelihood of lobbying against a proposal relative to not lobbying when net revenue increases.

The same behavior is observed with respect to increases in AVPROF (increases the likelihood of lobbying in favor by a factor of 1.381 compared with a factor of 2.227 for lobbying against) and TOTASS (increases the likelihood of lobbying in favor by a factor of 1.895 compared with a factor of6.321 for lobbying against). In the case of exploration costs (UPSTREAM), the likelihood of lobbying is observed only if the lobbying is against the proposals presented.

The results obtained by multinomial logistic regression give robustness to the consideration of size as a determining economic factor for companies to lobby via comment letters. Thus, there is still no evidence to reject hypothesis H1.

For modeling using Poisson regression (Table 10), regressions were performed considering the extent to which oil companies lobbied in favor of the proposals contained in the DPEA as opposed to not lobbying (panel A) and the extent to which companies lobbied against the proposals contained in the DPEA as opposed to not lobbying (panel B).

Table 10
Results of Poisson regression

The results contained in Table 10 show that all general parameters of the regressions performed can be considered valid because the statistical significance of the chi-square test was within the 1% level. In addition, McFadden's R2 ranged from 13% to 35%, which is a relatively low goodness-of-fit but consistent with the objectives of this study.

Starting with an analysis of the results that consider the extent to which companies lobbied in favor of the DPEA proposals (panel A), the net revenue (NETREV), average net profit (AVPROF) and total assets (TOTASS) variables show statistical significance and once again give robustness to the consideration of size as indicative ofcompanies' likelihood to lobbyvia comment letters.

It is also possible to show the statistical significance of the MANCOMP variable in the presence of the NETREV, AVPROF and TOTASS variables. This result was suggested somewhat in the binomial logistic regression analyses, and the Poisson regression confirms those analyses, demonstrating that this characteristic (having a performance-based management compensation plan) is relevant to lobbying in favor of the DPEA.

When the dependent variable considers the extent to which the company lobbied against the DPEA proposals, the results of the Poisson regression also point to the statistical relevance of the NETREV, AVPROF and TOTASS variables.

This evidence also supports Watts and Zimmerman's (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134. political cost hypothesis, i.e., large companies tend to lobby to obtain regulation that is more favorable to them. In the case of the Poisson regression, an analysis of the coefficients indicates that the propensity to reject a proposal in the DPEA is greater than the propensity toaccept a proposal in the DPEA; therefore, lobbying is conductedto reject any change to the status quo.

Interestingly, exploration costs (UPSTREAM) were not significant in either of the Poisson regression models (regressions 11 and 15), which is inconsistent with expectations.

Based on thePoisson regression results, it appears that regardless of the extent to which a company was in favor of or against the DPEA proposals, size and the existence of a performance-based management compensation plan (marginally) represent determining factors for lobbying by the oil companies. This finding indicates that companies with these characteristics tend to have a lobbyist posture, either for or against accounting regulations regarding extractive activities, which supports the theory developed throughout this study.

With respect to the formulated test hypotheses, there is no evidence to reject hypothesis H1, and hypothesis H2 cannot be completely ruled out.

This study attempted to establish a conclusive analysis regarding the variables representing size, because these variables serve to explain the same phenomenon and are highly correlated. For that purpose, this study conducted technical factor analysis (Table 11) to establish a factor representative of size that could be used as a dependent variable in binomial and multinomial logisticregressions and in Poisson regression.

Table 11
Regressions after factor analysis

Factor analysis assumptions were met: normality of the variables (except for UPSTREAM); significant correlations between NETREV, UPSTREAM, AVPROF and TOTASS variables; adequacy of the sample to factor analysis, with a Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO) measure of 0.826; and, finally, inequality between the correlation matrix and the identity matrix, with Bartlett's sphericity test being highly significant (p< 0.001).

Principal component analysis (PCA) was used to obtain the factors. PCA seeks to summarize most of the variance of the variables in a minimum number of factors. Using the Kaiser criterion (discarding eigenvalues ​​less than 1 due to their insignificance), it was possible to define a single factor that explained 86.1% of data variance. The results of factor analysis are presented in Appendix 1 Appendix 1 Factor Analysis Results Table KMO, Bartlett and Communalities test Measures Value Communalities Variables Initial Extraction Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO) Test NETREV 1.000 0.878 Sample Adequacy 0.826 UPSTREAM 1.000 0.805 Bartlett's Sphericity Test Chi-Square 607.017 AVPROF 1.000 0.864 df 6 Significance 0.000 TOTASS 1.000 0.896 Table Eigenvalues and percentage of variance explained by factors Components Initial Eigenvalues Percentage of Explained Variance Total % of Variance % Accumulated Total % of Variance % Accumulated 1 3.443 86.080% 86.080% 3.443 86.080% 86.080% 2 0.270 6.749% 92.829% 3 0.192 4.797% 97.627% 4 0.095 2.373% 100.000% Table Factor loadings and coefficient matrix of factor scores Factor Loadings Matrix of Coefficients of Factor Scores Variables Component1 Variables Component1 NETREV 0.937 NETREV 0.272 UPSTREAM 0.897 UPSTREAM 0.261 AVPROF 0.929 AVPROF 0.270 TOTASS 0.946 TOTASS 0.275 .

Thus, based on the values ​​of the coefficients of the factor scores for each of the four variables (NETREV, UPSTREAM, AVPROF and TOTASS), the factor analysis establishes a new predictor variable named "SIZE". New regressions were generated using this variable; the results are shown in Table 11.

The results demonstrate and confirm the previous findings that size is a relevant feature that increases the likelihood that a company will lobby via comment letter. In all cases (regressions 18 to 22), the size variable was statistically significant. Analyzing the coefficients obtained, the likelihood is greater that lobbying in general will be against the DPEA proposals.

However, this configuration does not confirm the relevance of management compensation plans (MANCOMP) to the likelihood of lobbying via comment letter. In the situations tested, there was statistical significance only when the extent of agreement (disagreement) with the DPEA proposals was tested using Poisson regression (regression 21), and such significance was marginal.

5 CONCLUSIONS

The results are robust and support the fact that there are determining factors in the adoption of lobbying strategies by oil companies regarding established (or proposed) accounting regulations. The results also confirm the political cost hypothesis (the size hypothesis) advocated by Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., which holds that large companies tend to lobby standard setters on accounting regulation toobtain standards that meet their needs.

The size factor was modeled using different approaches and proved relevant in all econometric models used, which supports the hypothesis that large oil companies are more likely to lobby. This trend was especially evident for companies that were predominantly opposed to the proposals in the DPEA.

The evidence also indicates, in a marginal way, that oil companies with performance-based management compensation plans are more likely to lobby than other oil companies, as was previously demonstrated by Watts and Zimmerman (1978)Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134., Deakin (1989)Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151. and Georgiou and Roberts (2004)Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453..

By combining the results, one can infer that large companies in the oil industry will lobby against changes to the status quo when the IASB attempts to introduce new accounting regulations for the oil industry. In other words, financial statement preparers are in favor of the use of historical cost as the basis for asset value and the freedom to choose between two different accounting methods (successful efforts and full cost). Furthermore, they are opposed to changes that would increase disclosure requirements.

From the perspective of institutional theory, the IASB's due process for standard setting seeks high levels of participation by its constituents at all stages of standard development to make the standard-setting process more neutral and legitimate. At the same time, according to theeconomic theory of regulation, companies participate in the due process of standard setting to obtain standards that benefit themselves.

Therefore, considering that standard-setting by the IASBis a political process characterized by the interaction of numerous conflicting interests, it is expected that the review/replacement ofIFRS 6by the IASB will be complex and subject to significant pressure from oil companies to maintain the status quo. All of this reinforces Larson's (2002)Larson, R. K. (2002). The IASC's search for legitimacy: an analysis of the IASC's Standing Interpretations Committee. Advances in International Accounting, 15,79-120. argument that due to external and political factors, the IASB may adopt less neutral positions toaccommodate its constituents' interests; it also supports the possibility that the review/replacement of IFRS 6 by the IASB could be captured by the oil industry, as suggested by Cortese, Irvine, and Kaidonis (2010)Cortese, C. L., Irvine, H. J., & Kaidonis, M. A. (2010) Powerful players: how constituents captured the setting of IFRS 6, an accounting standard for extractive industries., Accounting Forum 34,76-88..

The results presented in this study pertain only to oil companies and cannot be generalized to other economic sectors or to the overall IASB standard-setting process. However, the econometric models used in this study can be generalized and reproduced in other studies, particularly the models that use multinomial and Poisson regressions, which are new to research onlobbying on accounting regulation.

Although the concept of lobbying used here has been widely used in the accounting literature, it limits the results of this study, given that the submission of comment letters to the IASB's public consultation was the only lobbying activity considered. Therefore, other modeling studies could be conducted to expand on the present study; for example, future studies could use questionnaires and interviews to include other forms of lobbying in the analysis, similar to the work performed by Georgiou (2004)Georgiou, G. (2004). Corporate lobbying on accounting standards: methods, timing and perceived effectiveness. Abacus, 40(2),219-237..

In addition, it is important to note that the proxies used to define firms' characteristics are not necessarily limited to those used here, and other economic determinants may be possible. Moreover, the variables used here - especially the variables relating to restrictive covenants (COVENANT) and management compensation (MANCOMP) - may take on other dimensions. For example, instead of assuming only binary values ​​(0 or 1), the MANCOMP variable could be modeled as a continuous variable representing, e.g., the percentage of a manager's total compensation attributable to variable compensation, based on the hypothesis that a greater dependence on variable compensation makes it more likely that the manager will make accounting choices that benefit him or her.

Finally, the limitations inherent in the use of the Evaluate Energy ® database must be reported because it is necessary to consider the possibility of errors in data entry (as is true with respect to all databases). Thus, judgments regarding the integrity of the database may represent researcher bias.

  • *
    Paper presented at the VII Congresso Anpcont, Fortaleza, Brazil, 2013.

Annex 1

Questions presented by the IASB in the discussion paper Extractive Activities

Question # 1: Do you agree that the scope of an extractive activities IFRS should include only upstream activities for minerals, oil and gas?

Question # 2: Do you agree that there should be a single accounting and disclosure model thatapplies to both the minerals industry and the oil and gasindustry?

Question # 3: Do you agree that the mineral reserves and resource definitions established by the Committee for Mineral Reserves International Reporting Standards and that oil and gas reserve and resource definitions established by the Society of Petroleum Engineers (together with other industry bodies) should be used in an IFRS for extractive activities?

Question # 4: Do you agree that legal rights, such as rights of exploration and extraction, should be the basis for recognizing mineral or oil and gas assets and that the information obtained from subsequent exploration and evaluation activities and development works to access minerals or oil and gas deposits should be treated as enhancements of these legal rights?

Question # 5: Do you agree that the geographical boundary of the unit of account for a minerals or oil and gas property should be defined initially based on the exploration rights held, and that as exploration, evaluation and development activities take place, the unit of account would contract progressively until it becomes no greater than a single area or group of contiguous areas for which the legal rights are held and which is expected to generate largely independent cash flows?

Question # 6: Do you agree that mineralsand oil and gas assets should be measured based on historical cost but that detailed information should be disclosed toenhance the relevance of the financial statements?

Question # 7: Do you agree that exploration properties should not be tested for impairment in accordance with IAS 36 and that an exploration property should be written down to its recoverable amount in those cases where management has enough information to make this determination?

Question # 8: Do you agree that the disclosure goals for extractive activities are to enable users of financial statements to evaluate: (a) the value attributable to an entity's minerals or oil and gas assets; (b) the contribution of these assets to current period financial performance; and (c) the nature and extent of the risks and uncertainties associated with these assets?

Question # 9: Do you agree that information to be disclosed in the explanatory notes of financial statements should include: (a) quantities of proved reserves and proved plus probable reserves, with reserve quantities disclosed separately by commodity and material geographical area; (b) the main assumptions used in estimating reserves quantities and a sensitivity analysis; (c) a reconciliation of changes in reserve quantity estimates from year to year; (d) a current value measurement that corresponds to reserves quantities disclosed with a reconciliation of changes in current value measurement from year to year; (e) separate identification of the exploration, development and production cash flows for the current period and as a time seriesover a defined period (for example, five years); and (f) separate identification of production revenues by commodity?

Question # 10: Do you believe that a requirement to disclosethe payments made by an entity to governments on a country-by-country basis is justifiable on cost-benefit grounds?

Appendix 1

Factor Analysis Results
Table
KMO, Bartlett and Communalities test
Table
Eigenvalues and percentage of variance explained by factors
Table
Factor loadings and coefficient matrix of factor scores

Referências

  • Asekomeh, A. O., Russel, A., & Tarbert, H. (2006). A critical analysis of the use of accounting standards' comment letters as lobbying tools by extractive industry firms. Petroleum Accounting and Financial Management Journal, 25(3),55-57.
  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98,371-400.
  • Bengtsson, E. (2011). Repoliticalization of accounting standard setting - the IASB, the EU and the global financial crisis. Critical Perspectives on Accounting, 22,567-580.
  • Chatham, M. D., Larson, R. K., & Vietze, A. (2010). Issues affecting the development of an international accounting standard on financial instruments. Advances in Accounting, incorporating Advances in International Accounting, 26,97-107.
  • Chung, D. Y. (1999). The informational effect of corporate lobbying against proposed accounting standards. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 12(3),243-269.
  • Collins, D. W., Dent, W. T., & O'Connor, M. (1978November/December). Market effects of the elimination of full cost accounting in the oil and gas industry. Financial Analysts Journal, 48-56.
  • Collins, D. W., Rozeff, M. S., & Salatka, W. K. (1982). The SEC's rejection of SFAS nº 19: tests of market price reversal. The Accounting Review, 57(1),1-17.
  • Corrar, L. J., Paulo, E., & Dias Filho, J. M. (2007). Análise multivariada São Paulo: Atlas.
  • Cortese, C. L., Irvine, H. J., & Kaidonis, M. A. (2009). Extractive industries accounting and economic consequences: past, present and future. Accounting Forum, 33,27-37.
  • Cortese, C. L., Irvine, H. J., & Kaidonis, M. A. (2010) Powerful players: how constituents captured the setting of IFRS 6, an accounting standard for extractive industries., Accounting Forum 34,76-88.
  • Deakin, E. B. (1979). An analysis of differences between non-major oil firms using successful efforts and full cost methods. The Accounting Review, 54(4),722-734.
  • Deakin, E. B. (1989). Rational economic behavior and lobbying on accounting issues: evidence from the oil and gas industry., The Accounting Review 64(1),137-151.
  • Dhaliwal, D. S. (1982). Some economic determinants of management lobbying for alternative methods of accounting: evidence from the accounting for interest costs issue. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 9(2),255-265.
  • Fávero, L. P., Belfiore, P., Silva, F. L., & Chan, B. L. (2009). Análise de dados: modelagem multivariada para tomada de decisões Rio de Janeiro: Elsevier.
  • Fields, T. D., Lys, T. Z., & Vicent, L. (2001). Empirical research on accounting choice. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31,255-307.
  • Fogarty, T. J. (1992). Financial accounting standard setting as an institutionalized action field: constraints, opportunities and dilemmas. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 11,331-355.
  • Francis, J. R. (1987). Lobbying against proposed accounting standards: the case of employers' pension accounting., Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 6(1),35-57.
  • Francis, J. (2001). Discussion of empirical research on accounting choice., Journal of Accounting and Economics 31,309-319.
  • Georgiou, G. (2004). Corporate lobbying on accounting standards: methods, timing and perceived effectiveness. Abacus, 40(2),219-237.
  • Georgiou, G. (2005). Investigating corporate management lobbying in the U.K. accounting standard-setting process: a multi-issue/multi-period approach., Abacus 41(3),323-347.
  • Georgiou, G. (2010). The IASB standard-setting process: participation and perceptions of financial statement users. The British Accounting Review, 42,103-118.
  • Georgiou, G., & Roberts, C. B. (2004). Corporate lobbying in the UK: an analysis of attitudes towards the ASB's 1995 deferred taxation proposals., The British Accounting Review 36(4),441-453.
  • Giner, B., & Arce, M. (2012). Lobbying on accounting standards: evidence from IFRS 2 on share-based payments. European Accounting Review, 21(4),655-691.
  • Hansen, T. B. (20011). Lobbying of the IASB: an empirical investigation. Journal of International Accounting Research, 10(2),57-75.
  • Hill, N. T., Shelton, S. W., & Stevens, K. T. (2002). Corporate lobbying behavior on accounting for stock-based compensation: venue and format choices., Abacus 38(1),78-90.
  • Holthausen, R. W., & Leftwich, R. W. (1983 August). The economic consequences of accounting choice: implications of costly contracting and monitoring., Journal of Accounting and Economics 5,77-117.
  • Kenny, S. Y., & Larson, R. (1993). Lobbying behavior and the development of international accounting standards: the case of the IASC's joint venture project., European Accounting Review 2(3),531-554.
  • King, T. A. (2006). More than a numbers game: a brief history of accounting. New Jersey: Wiley.
  • Koh, W. C. (2011). What drives firms' decisions to lobby and determinants of their lobbying positions: evidence from firms' comment letter submissions during FASB's stock option expensing proposal in 2004. The International Journal of Accounting, 46,1-24.
  • Kothari, S. P., Ramanna, K., & Skinner, D. J. (2010). Implications for GAAP from an analysis of positive research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50,246-286.
  • Larson, R. K. (1997). Corporate lobbying of the international accounting standards committee. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting, 8(3),175-203.
  • Larson, R. K. (2002). The IASC's search for legitimacy: an analysis of the IASC's Standing Interpretations Committee. Advances in International Accounting, 15,79-120.
  • Larson, R. K. (2008). An examination of comment letters to the IASC: special purpose entities. Research in Accounting Regulation, 20,27-46.
  • Larson, R. K., & Kenny, S. Y. (2011). Journal of International Accounting, Auditing and Taxation, 20,1-19.
  • Macarthur, J. B. (1988). An analysis of the content of corporate submissions on proposed accounting standards in the UK. Accounting and Business Research, 18(71),213-226.
  • Matos, E. B. S., Gonçalves, R. S., Niyama, J. K., & Marques, M. M., (2013). Convergência internacional: análise da relação entre o processo normativo e a composição dos membros do IASB. Advances in Scientific and Applied Accounting, 6(1),66-91.
  • Mcleay, S., Ordelheide, D., & Young, S. (2000). Constituent lobbying and its impact on the development of financial reporting regulations: evidence from Germany. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 25(1),79-98.
  • Meier, H. H., Alam, P., & Pearson, M. A. (1993). Auditor lobbying for accounting standards: the case of banks and savings and loan associations., Accounting and Business Research 23(92),477-487.
  • Ndubizu, G. A., Choi, Y. C., & Jain, R. (1993). Corporate lobbying strategy and pension accounting deliberations: an empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8(3),277-287.
  • Oliveira, N. A. L., Costa Júnior, J. V., & Silva, A. H. C. (2013). Regulação contábil no Brasil: uma análise dos processos de audiência pública do comitê de pronunciamentos contábeis (CPC) nos anos de 2007 a 2011., Advances in Scientific and Applied Accounting 6(1),49-65.
  • Orens, R., Jorissen, A., Lybaert, N., & Tas, L. V. D. (2011). Corporate lobbying in private accounting standard setting: does the IASB have to reckon with national differences? Accounting in Europe, 8(2),211-234.
  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2),211-240.
  • Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2),335-358.
  • Saemann, G. (1999). An examination of comment letters filed in the U.S. financial accounting standard-setting process by institutional interest groups. Abacus, 35(1),1-28.
  • Santos, O. M., Lopes, A. B., & Silva, P. D. A. (2010 julho). Value relevance dos métodos contábeis full cost e successful effort sem empresas petrolíferas e considerações sobre a futura norma internacional das atividades extrativistas. Anais do Congresso USP de Controladoria e Contabilidade, São Paulo, SP, Brasil, 10.
  • Solomons, D. (1978). The politicization of accounting. Journal of Accountancy, 146(5),65-72.
  • Stenka, R., & Taylor, P. (2010). Setting UK standards on the concept of control: an analysis of lobbying behavior., Accounting and Business Research 40(2),109-130.
  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation., The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2(1),3-21.
  • Sutton, T. G. (1984). Lobbying of accounting standard-setting bodies in the U.K. and the U.S.A.: a Downsian analysis., Accounting, Organizations and Society 9(1),81-95.
  • Tandy, P. R., & Wilburn, N. L. (1996). The academic community's participation in standard setting: submission of comment letters on SFAS nºs 1-117. Accounting Horizons, 10(3),92-111.
  • Tavares, M. F. N., Paulo, E., Anjos, L. C. M., & Carter, D. (2013). Contribuições ao exposure draft revenue from contracts with costumers: análise das opiniões das firmas sobre a obrigação de desempenho onerosa. Revista de Contabilidade do Mestrado em Ciências Contábeis da UERJ, 18(2),14-27.
  • Tutticci, I., Dunstan, K., & Holmes, S. (1994). Respondent lobbying in the Australian accounting standard-setting process: ED49 - a case study. Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal, 7(2),86-104 .
  • Viscusi, W. K., Harrington, J. E., Jr., & Vernon, J. M. (2005). Economics of regulation and antitrust (4th ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press.
  • Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a positive theory of the determination of accounting standards., The Accounting Review 53(1),112-134.
  • Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1986). Positive accounting theory New Jersey: Prentice-Hall.
  • Weetman, P., Davie, E. S., & Collins, W. (1996). Lobbying on accounting issues: prepar/user imbalance in the case of the operating and financial review., Accounting, Auditing and Accountability Journal 9(1),59-76.
  • Zeff, S. A. (2002). "Political" lobbying on proposed standards: a challenge to the IASB., Accounting Horizons 16(1),43-54.
  • Zeff, S. A. (2005February). The evolution of U.S. GAAP: the political forces behind professional standards. The CPA Journal, 21-29.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    May-Aug 2014

History

  • Received
    23 Sept 2013
  • Reviewed
    30 Sept 2013
  • Accepted
    04 June 2014
Universidade de São Paulo, Faculdade de Economia, Administração e Contabilidade, Departamento de Contabilidade e Atuária Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908 - prédio 3 - sala 118, 05508 - 010 São Paulo - SP - Brasil, Tel.: (55 11) 2648-6320, Tel.: (55 11) 2648-6321, Fax: (55 11) 3813-0120 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: recont@usp.br